Age, Biography and Wiki

Giovanni Dosi was born on 25 August, 1953 in Fiorenzuola d'Arda, Italy, is an Italian economist (1953–). Discover Giovanni Dosi's Biography, Age, Height, Physical Stats, Dating/Affairs, Family and career updates. Learn How rich is he in this year and how he spends money? Also learn how he earned most of networth at the age of 70 years old?

Popular As N/A
Occupation N/A
Age 70 years old
Zodiac Sign Virgo
Born 25 August, 1953
Birthday 25 August
Birthplace Fiorenzuola d'Arda, Italy
Nationality Ytaly

We recommend you to check the complete list of Famous People born on 25 August. He is a member of famous economist with the age 70 years old group.

Giovanni Dosi Height, Weight & Measurements

At 70 years old, Giovanni Dosi height not available right now. We will update Giovanni Dosi's Height, weight, Body Measurements, Eye Color, Hair Color, Shoe & Dress size soon as possible.

Physical Status
Height Not Available
Weight Not Available
Body Measurements Not Available
Eye Color Not Available
Hair Color Not Available

Dating & Relationship status

He is currently single. He is not dating anyone. We don't have much information about He's past relationship and any previous engaged. According to our Database, He has no children.

Family
Parents Not Available
Wife Not Available
Sibling Not Available
Children Not Available

Giovanni Dosi Net Worth

His net worth has been growing significantly in 2023-2024. So, how much is Giovanni Dosi worth at the age of 70 years old? Giovanni Dosi’s income source is mostly from being a successful economist. He is from Ytaly. We have estimated Giovanni Dosi's net worth, money, salary, income, and assets.

Net Worth in 2024 $1 Million - $5 Million
Salary in 2024 Under Review
Net Worth in 2023 Pending
Salary in 2023 Under Review
House Not Available
Cars Not Available
Source of Income economist

Giovanni Dosi Social Network

Instagram
Linkedin
Twitter
Facebook
Wikipedia Giovanni Dosi Wikipedia
Imdb

Timeline

Giovanni Dosi is Professor of Economics and Director of the Institute of Economics at the Scuola Superiore Sant'Anna in Pisa.

He is the Co-Director of the task forces “Industrial Policy” and “Intellectual Property” at the Initiative for Policy Dialogue at Columbia University.

Dosi is Continental European Editor of Industrial and Corporate Change.

Included in ISI Highly Cited Researchers.

His major research areas, where he is author and editor of several works, include economics of innovation and technological change, industrial organization and industrial dynamics, theory of the firm and corporate governance, evolutionary theory, economic growth and development.

A selection of his works has been published in two volumes: ''Innovation, Organization and Economic Dynamics.

2000

Selected Essays, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, 2000; and Economic Organization, Industrial Dynamics and Development: Selected Essays'', Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, 2012.

Giovanni Dosi's economic analysis is characterized by the contemporaneous attempt to (i) identify empirical regularities and (ii) provide micro-foundations consistent with such regularities.

As such, his work is a mix of statistical investigations and theoretical efforts.

Throughout his work Dosi and his co-authors have identified some stylized facts as being especially relevant for economic analysis, among others:

2019

S.F.1 Over the 19th-20th century technological innovation has proved to be the major contributor to the economic growth of countries, whose growth rates have however displayed an expanding variance.

S.F.2 The learning processes that firms undertake to carry out innovations are characterized by trials, errors and unexpected success.

S.F.3 Firms are highly heterogeneous in terms of sizes, productivities, and profitabilities.

In particular, firm sizes display stationary skewed distributions, while productivities and profitabilities display stationary wide supports of their fat tailed distributions.

These facts have led Dosi to point out some theoretical implications, which raise contradictions within Neoclassical economics and bear favorable witness to Evolutionary economics.

The role of technological progress as an explanation of contemporary economic growth (S.F.1) has led Dosi to carefully analyze the nature of technology.

In particular, he has suggested an interpretation of technical change resting on the concepts of technological paradigm and technology trajectory.

In analogy with Thomas Kuhn's definition of a scientific paradigm, Dosi has defined a technological paradigm as the general outlook on the productive problems faced by firms.

As such, a technological paradigm is composed by some sort of model of the technology at stake (e.g. the model of a microprocessor) and by the specific technological problems posed by such model (e.g. increasing computational capacity, reducing dimensions, etc.).

Therefore, technology is identified as a problem-solving activity in which the problems to be solved are selected by the paradigm itself.

In this sense, a technological paradigm entails strong prescriptions on the direction of technological change, that is the direction toward which future technical improvements will converge.

Such gradual improvements along the specific lines prescribed by the paradigm are what constitute technological trajectories and progress.

Such interpretation of technological change brings Dosi to identify a limited influence of market signals on the direction of technological change.

More precisely, in his view relative prices might affect the direction of technological change only within the boundaries defined by the nature of the technological paradigm.

Such idea can be better understood by analyzing the effect of market signals in their two possible directions: moving "downstream" (i.e. from the technology to the sale of goods) and "upstream" (i.e. from the market environment to the technology).

Going "downstream", from the technology to the sale of goods, market signals enter the picture at opposite stages.

First, market signals can act ex ante in the competition among different paradigms: if more paradigms are available, firms would select one or the other according to their expected profitability.

But once a paradigm is affirmed, the direction of technological change would be already implied by its technological prescriptions.

Second, market signals can act by selecting ex post those applications of the affirmed paradigm (i.e. the final products) that best fit the market requests.

However, at that point their impact on the direction of technical change would be null, since such direction had already been decided by the prescriptions of the affirmed paradigm.

Going "upstream", from the market environment to the technology, market signals act to inform the producers of the technology about variations in relative prices.

However, the extent to which technology producers can shift from more expensive to cheaper inputs, or modify technology toward the use of cheaper complement goods is bound by technical constraints.

Such constraints emerge because inputs are characterized by low substitutability due to the physical and chemical limits involved in the production process.

Consequently, the upstream incentives given by market signals affect only the rate of use of certain inputs as well as the rate of development of a trajectory but not the direction of technical change, which is bound by the technical constraints of production.

The trial and error procedures adopted by firms to improve along a technological trajectory (S.F.2) have taken Dosi to assess the issue of uncertainty.

At a general level, trial and error procedures imply that firms might not be able to forecast completely the outcome of a choice they make; in fact, if they could foresee the error, they would presumably avoid it because it is costly.

Such a fact is strongly at odds with any assumption of "perfect rationality" or "farsightedness" on the side of economic agents, which is a foundational element of the Neoclassical approach.

Dosi has analyzed this issue by assessing the ways in which economic agents perceive and deal with choices that have an uncertain outcome.

In analogy with Herbert A. Simon's distinction about rationality, he has proposed the distinction between substantive uncertainty and procedural uncertainty.

In his view, "the former is related to some lack of information about environmental events, while the latter concerns the competence gap in problem-solving".