Age, Biography and Wiki

Mark McClellan was born on 26 June, 1963 in Austin, Texas, U.S., is an American health economist (born 1963). Discover Mark McClellan's Biography, Age, Height, Physical Stats, Dating/Affairs, Family and career updates. Learn How rich is he in this year and how he spends money? Also learn how he earned most of networth at the age of 60 years old?

Popular As N/A
Occupation N/A
Age 60 years old
Zodiac Sign Cancer
Born 26 June 1963
Birthday 26 June
Birthplace Austin, Texas, U.S.
Nationality

We recommend you to check the complete list of Famous People born on 26 June. He is a member of famous economist with the age 60 years old group.

Mark McClellan Height, Weight & Measurements

At 60 years old, Mark McClellan height not available right now. We will update Mark McClellan's Height, weight, Body Measurements, Eye Color, Hair Color, Shoe & Dress size soon as possible.

Physical Status
Height Not Available
Weight Not Available
Body Measurements Not Available
Eye Color Not Available
Hair Color Not Available

Dating & Relationship status

He is currently single. He is not dating anyone. We don't have much information about He's past relationship and any previous engaged. According to our Database, He has no children.

Family
Parents Not Available
Wife Not Available
Sibling Not Available
Children Not Available

Mark McClellan Net Worth

His net worth has been growing significantly in 2023-2024. So, how much is Mark McClellan worth at the age of 60 years old? Mark McClellan’s income source is mostly from being a successful economist. He is from . We have estimated Mark McClellan's net worth, money, salary, income, and assets.

Net Worth in 2024 $1 Million - $5 Million
Salary in 2024 Under Review
Net Worth in 2023 Pending
Salary in 2023 Under Review
House Not Available
Cars Not Available
Source of Income economist

Mark McClellan Social Network

Instagram
Linkedin
Twitter
Facebook
Wikipedia Mark McClellan Wikipedia
Imdb

Timeline

1963

Mark Barr McClellan (born June 26, 1963) is the director of the Robert J Margolis Center for Health Policy and the Margolis Professor of Business, Medicine and Health Policy at Duke University.

1980

Implemented in the 1980s, PPS was intended to incentivize hospitals to drive down costs by limiting the use of costly technologies that added little benefit.

The hallmark of the program is the use of fixed payments via diagnosis-related groups (DRGs) in a prospective manner based on diagnosis at the time of admission.

McClellan suggests that PPS may not optimally incentivize cost sharing among insurers and health providers due to the income effect by which hospitals may seek out particular diagnoses with higher reimbursement rates, akin to skimming in the insurance arena.

Conversely, retrospective cost sharing allows for possible supply induced demand, minimizing the hospital's incentive to decrease resource utilization and costs in more complicated cases.

This paper presents an econometric model to summarize these reimbursement incentives, present information on cost sharing and generosity in the PPS model, and discuss the implications of these findings.

McClellan points out repeatedly that the PPS has increasingly permitted more retrospective adjustments to the payments.

This has been primarily driven through outliers and treatment-driven DRG's developed during the admission, rather than diagnosis-driven DRG's identified at the time of admission.

Outlier payments allow for supplemental payments for unusually lengthy or expensive admissions and make up no more than 5% of all hospital admissions.

The author considers the increase in case mix index, a measure of the intensity of care delivered, to have the most important influence on overall PPS payments.

He adds that these retrospective adjustments may be hampering the program's effectiveness in implementing cost sharing.

McClellan's model allows individual aspects of PPS to be evaluated for their contribution to cost sharing rates and reimbursement variance.

He used linear regression to approximate how the cost sharing reimbursement is derived, using fixed and variable components.

Lower costs equaled lower reimbursement; however, higher costs led to higher reimbursements only if the costs were driven by a procedure.

This was most true for men aged 65 to 69 with surgery requiring ICU care and an increased length of stay.

Generosity estimates indicate that virtually all hospitals do some cost sharing.

Higher generosity is usually associated with greater retrospective limits on cost sharing.

1985

After graduating from the University of Texas in 1985 majoring in English, Biology, and Plan II, he earned his M.D. degree from the Harvard–MIT Division of Health Sciences and Technology in 1992 and his Ph.D. in economics from MIT in 1993.

1991

He also earned a Master of Public Administration degree from Harvard Kennedy School in 1991.

He completed his residency training in internal medicine at Brigham and Women's Hospital, and he is board-certified in internal medicine.

McClellan's research studies have addressed measuring and improving the quality of health care, the economic and policy factors influencing medical treatment decisions and health outcomes, estimating the effects of medical treatments, technological change in health care and its consequences for health and medical expenditures, and the relationship between health and economic well-being.

He has twice received the Arrow Award for Outstanding Research in Health Economics.

1997

Published in 1997 in the Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, McClellan's paper serves as a review and analysis of provider payment incentives resulting from the Medicare prospective payment system (PPS).

1998

From 1998 to 1999, McClellan served as deputy assistant secretary of the Treasury for Economic Policy, where he supervised economic analysis and policy development on a wide range of domestic policy issues.

2001

During 2001 and 2002, McClellan served in the White House.

He was a member of the president's Council of Economic Advisers, where he advised on domestic economic issues.

He also served during this time as a senior policy director for health care and related economic issues for the White House.

2002

Formerly, he was a senior fellow and director of the Health Care Innovation and Value Initiative at the Engelberg Center for Health Care Reform at The Brookings Institution, in Washington, D.C. McClellan served as commissioner of the United States Food and Drug Administration under President George W. Bush from 2002 through 2004, and subsequently as administrator of the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services from 2004 through 2006.

McClellan served as commissioner for the Food and Drug Administration (FDA) beginning November 14, 2002, becoming the first economist to hold that position.

Originally from Austin, Texas, he is the brother of former White House Press Secretary Scott McClellan and the son of Texas comptroller Carole Keeton Strayhorn and attorney Barr McClellan.

2004

He was administrator for the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services in the United States Department of Health and Human Services from 2004 to 2006.

In this position, he was responsible for administering the Medicare and Medicaid programs, including Medicare Part D, the prescription drug benefit program engendered by the Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, and Modernization Act.

Following the resignation of Health & Human Services Secretary Tommy Thompson in 2004, McClellan was mentioned as a possible replacement, but President Bush ultimately nominated former Utah governor Mike Leavitt.

2006

On September 5, 2006, McClellan announced his resignation from his post in the department.

He told The Associated Press he would be leaving the agency in about five weeks and would probably work for a think tank where he could write about improving health care in the United States.

2007

In 2007, he was appointed as the chair of the Reagan-Udall Foundation, a public-private partnership between the U.S. Food and Drug Administration and industry.

Previously, McClellan was associate professor of economics at Stanford University, associate professor of medicine at the Stanford University School of Medicine, a practicing internist, and director of the Program on Health Outcomes Research at Stanford University.

He was also a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research and a visiting scholar at the American Enterprise Institute.

Additionally, he was a member of the National Cancer Policy Board of the National Academy of Sciences, associate editor of the Journal of Health Economics, and co-principal investigator of the Health and Retirement Study (HRS), a longitudinal study of the health and economic well-being of older Americans.

==== Hospital Reimbursement Incentives: An Empirical Analysis ====