Age, Biography and Wiki
Arnold Harberger was born on 27 July, 1924 in Newark, New Jersey, U.S., is an American economist (born 1924). Discover Arnold Harberger's Biography, Age, Height, Physical Stats, Dating/Affairs, Family and career updates. Learn How rich is he in this year and how he spends money? Also learn how he earned most of networth at the age of 99 years old?
Popular As |
N/A |
Occupation |
N/A |
Age |
99 years old |
Zodiac Sign |
Leo |
Born |
27 July 1924 |
Birthday |
27 July |
Birthplace |
Newark, New Jersey, U.S. |
Nationality |
United States
|
We recommend you to check the complete list of Famous People born on 27 July.
He is a member of famous economist with the age 99 years old group.
Arnold Harberger Height, Weight & Measurements
At 99 years old, Arnold Harberger height not available right now. We will update Arnold Harberger's Height, weight, Body Measurements, Eye Color, Hair Color, Shoe & Dress size soon as possible.
Physical Status |
Height |
Not Available |
Weight |
Not Available |
Body Measurements |
Not Available |
Eye Color |
Not Available |
Hair Color |
Not Available |
Dating & Relationship status
He is currently single. He is not dating anyone. We don't have much information about He's past relationship and any previous engaged. According to our Database, He has no children.
Family |
Parents |
Not Available |
Wife |
Not Available |
Sibling |
Not Available |
Children |
Not Available |
Arnold Harberger Net Worth
His net worth has been growing significantly in 2023-2024. So, how much is Arnold Harberger worth at the age of 99 years old? Arnold Harberger’s income source is mostly from being a successful economist. He is from United States. We have estimated Arnold Harberger's net worth, money, salary, income, and assets.
Net Worth in 2024 |
$1 Million - $5 Million |
Salary in 2024 |
Under Review |
Net Worth in 2023 |
Pending |
Salary in 2023 |
Under Review |
House |
Not Available |
Cars |
Not Available |
Source of Income |
economist |
Arnold Harberger Social Network
Instagram |
|
Linkedin |
|
Twitter |
|
Facebook |
|
Wikipedia |
|
Imdb |
|
Timeline
Arnold Carl Harberger (born July 27, 1924) is an American economist.
His approach to the teaching and practice of economics is to emphasize the use of analytical tools that are directly applicable to real-world issues.
His influence on academic economics is reflected in part by the widespread use of the term "Harberger triangle" to refer to the standard graphical depiction of the efficiency cost of distortions of competitive equilibrium.
His influence on the practice of economic policy is manifested by the high positions attained by his followers in national agencies such as central banks and ministries of finance, and in international agencies such as the World Bank.
Harberger completed his B.A. in economics at Johns Hopkins University, and his M.A. in international relations in 1947 and his Ph.D. in economics in 1950 at the University of Chicago.
After teaching at Johns Hopkins, Harberger returned to the University of Chicago to teach full-time from 1953 to 1982, and part-time from 1984 to 1991.
He married Chilean Anita Valjalo in 1958.
Since 1984, he has been a professor at the University of California, Los Angeles, serving as professor emeritus since 2014.
The core of those reforms has been continued by a succession of democratically elected governments in Chile since the end of the Pinochet government in 1990.
His former student Ricardo Ffrench-Davis has praised Harberger for being free of ideological prejudice, which according to Ffrench-Davis was not the case of Harberger's colleague Milton Friedman.
Harberger's Ph.D. thesis, written under Lloyd Metzler as committee chair and Kenneth Arrow and Franco Modigliani as advisers, was on international macroeconomic theory, but his academic reputation is primarily based on his work on the economics of taxation, welfare economics, and benefit-cost analysis.
Harberger's first contribution to applied welfare economics estimated that the efficiency loss from monopoly—or, more precisely, from prices exceeding marginal cost—in US manufacturing was unlikely to exceed 0.1% of GDP.
In making this estimate, Harberger assumed that the extent of market power of the firms in an industry is reflected in the degree of above-normal profits in that industry.
The efficiency loss from monopoly arises from the fact that high-profit industries produce too little output, and low-profit industries produce too much output.
The net welfare cost is the sum of the gains that would be obtained if output were reallocated in such a way as to bring the rate of profit in each industry to the economy-wide average.
To do this requires an estimate of the elasticity of demand for the output of each industry in his sample.
He argued that a value of -1 for this elasticity was on the high end of plausible values, because each industry consisted of more than one firm.
(The elasticity of demand facing a particular firm is inversely related to its market share. Harberger's assumption clearly implies that individual firms face elasticities far greater than -1, and is thereby fully consistent with the theory of pricing by firms with a degree of market power.) For Harberger's assumed value of demand elasticities, the cost of the resources that would be required to achieve the efficient change in an industry's rate of production is equal to the calculated excess profits in that industry.
Using the formula developed by Harold Hotelling, Harberger measured the efficiency loss from noncompetitive pricing in each industry as the excess of the implied willingness to pay by consumers for each increment to output over the estimated cost of that increment.
His conclusion was that monopoly power was not pervasive in the U.S. economy, so that the manufacturing sector could be treated as nearly competitive.
Over a decade later, Gordon Tullock argued that Harberger's estimate of the welfare cost of monopoly was low because some resources would be used to compete for or protect monopoly rents, but his argument applies principally to instances of non-price competition for protected status, as in the case of tariffs or restrictions on entry into an industry through government regulation.
Harberger's seminal paper on the corporate income tax pioneered the use of general-equilibrium modeling by recasting the classic Heckscher-Ohlin model of international trade as a model of one country with two sectors, one comprising incorporated firms subject to a tax on their net incomes and the other made up of unincorporated firms.
Harberger's approach laid the groundwork for the later use of computable general equilibrium analysis of the impact of taxes on an entire economy.
In Harberger's model, the output of both sectors is produced under conditions of constant returns to scale, using homogeneous labor and capital.
Labor is perfectly mobile, so wages are equalized between the two sectors.
The corporate income tax is a tax on the return to corporate capital.
There is no integration of the corporate and personal income taxes so any dividends are taxed twice.
In the long run, capital is also fully mobile between sectors.
Harberger's key insight was that the mobility of capital between sectors means that in long-run equilibrium the after-tax rate of return to capital is equalized between the two sectors.
In this way, the corporate income tax lowers the after-tax real rate of return to all owners of capital equally.
When the income of capital owners in the corporate sector is taxed, the initial after-tax rate of return on corporate capital falls, prompting a shift of capital to the untaxed sector.
This shift continues until the rate of return in the untaxed sector falls, and the before-tax rate of return in the corporate sector rises, by amounts sufficient to equalize the after-tax rate of return to capital in all uses.
The contraction of the corporate sector leads to a reduction in that sector's demand for labor and a fall in the output of that sector.
The two remained together until her death in 2011.
Harberger speaks fluent Spanish.
He is known for maintaining close ties with his former students, many of whom have held influential government posts throughout Latin America, especially in Chile.
Among his former students are 15 central-bank presidents and about 50 government ministers.
He takes pride in the work they have done to advance sound economic policy in many countries over many decades.
He has been criticized for giving economic advice to some authoritarian governments in Latin America.
In the case of Chile, Harberger's influence on the "free-market" reforms undertaken by the Pinochet regime (after the failure of its initial policies of direct economic control) was solely through former students of his, dubbed the Chicago Boys by commentators, who had agreed to work in that government to address the ongoing economic crisis.